You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/cagan_ree.md
+72-85
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -4,7 +4,7 @@ jupytext:
4
4
extension: .md
5
5
format_name: myst
6
6
format_version: 0.13
7
-
jupytext_version: 1.14.5
7
+
jupytext_version: 1.16.1
8
8
kernelspec:
9
9
display_name: Python 3 (ipykernel)
10
10
language: python
@@ -18,13 +18,10 @@ kernelspec:
18
18
19
19
We'll use linear algebra first to explain and then do some experiments with a "monetarist theory of price levels".
20
20
21
+
Economists call it a "monetary" or "monetarist" theory of price levels because effects on price levels occur via a central banks's decisions to print money supply.
21
22
22
-
23
-
24
-
Economist call it a "monetary" or "monetarist" theory of price levels because effects on price levels occur via a central banks's decisions to print money supply.
25
-
26
-
* a goverment's fiscal policies determine whether it **expenditures** exceed its **tax collections**
27
-
* if its expenditures exceeds it tax collections, the government can instruct the central bank to cover the difference by **printing money**
23
+
* a goverment's fiscal policies determine whether its *expenditures* exceed its *tax collections*
24
+
* if its expenditures exceed its tax collections, the government can instruct the central bank to cover the difference by *printing money*
28
25
* that leads to effects on the price level as price level path adjusts to equate the supply of money to the demand for money
29
26
30
27
Such a theory of price levels was described by Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace in chapter 5 of
@@ -42,11 +39,11 @@ Elemental forces at work in the fiscal theory of the price level help to underst
42
39
According to this theory, when the government persistently spends more than it collects in taxes and prints money to finance the shortfall (the "shortfall" is called the "government deficit"), it puts upward pressure on the price level and generates
43
40
persistent inflation.
44
41
45
-
The ''monetarist'' or ''fiscal theory of price levels" asserts that
42
+
The "monetarist" or "fiscal theory of price levels" asserts that
46
43
47
-
* to **start** a persistent inflation the government beings persistently to run a money-financed government deficit
44
+
* to *start* a persistent inflation the government beings persistently to run a money-financed government deficit
48
45
49
-
* to **stop** a persistent inflation the government stops persistently running a money-financed government deficit
46
+
* to *stop* a persistent inflation the government stops persistently running a money-financed government deficit
50
47
51
48
The model in this lecture is a "rational expectations" (or "perfect foresight") version of a model that Philip Cagan {cite}`Cagan` used to study the monetary dynamics of hyperinflations.
52
49
@@ -60,7 +57,7 @@ While Cagan didn't use that "rational expectations" version of the model, Thoma
60
57
61
58
Some of our quantitative experiments with the rational expectations version of the model are designed to illustrate how the fiscal theory explains the abrupt end of those big inflations.
62
59
63
-
In those experiments, we'll encounter an instance of a ''velocity dividend'' that has sometimes accompanied successful inflation stabilization programs.
60
+
In those experiments, we'll encounter an instance of a "velocity dividend" that has sometimes accompanied successful inflation stabilization programs.
64
61
65
62
To facilitate using linear matrix algebra as our main mathematical tool, we'll use a finite horizon version of the model.
66
63
@@ -90,7 +87,7 @@ To represent the model formally, let
90
87
* $T$ the horizon -- i.e., the last period for which the model will determine $p_t$
91
88
* $\pi_{T+1}^*$ the terminal rate of inflation between times $T$ and $T+1$.
92
89
93
-
The demand for real balances $\exp\left(\frac{m_t^d}{p_t}\right)$ is governed by the following version of the Cagan demand function
90
+
The demand for real balances $\exp\left(m_t^d - p_t\right)$ is governed by the following version of the Cagan demand function
We'll start by executing a version of our "experiment 1" in which the government implements a **foreseen** sudden permanent reduction in the rate of money creation at time $T_1$.
317
+
We'll start by executing a version of our "experiment 1" in which the government implements a *foreseen* sudden permanent reduction in the rate of money creation at time $T_1$.
329
318
330
-
The following code performs the experiment and plots outcomes.
At time $T_1$ when the "surprise" money growth rate change occurs, to satisfy
408
392
equation {eq}`eq:pformula2`, the log of real balances jumps
409
-
**upward** as $\pi_t$ jumps **downward**.
393
+
*upward* as $\pi_t$ jumps *downward*.
410
394
411
395
But in order for $m_t - p_t$ to jump, which variable jumps, $m_{T_1}$ or $p_{T_1}$?
412
396
@@ -428,7 +412,7 @@ $$
428
412
m_{T_1}^2 - m_{T_1}^1 = \alpha (\pi^1 - \pi^2)
429
413
$$ (eq:eqnmoneyjump)
430
414
431
-
By letting money jump according to equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` the monetary authority prevents the price level from **falling** at the moment that the unanticipated stabilization arrives.
415
+
By letting money jump according to equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` the monetary authority prevents the price level from *falling* at the moment that the unanticipated stabilization arrives.
432
416
433
417
In various research papers about stabilizations of high inflations, the jump in the money supply described by equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` has been called
434
418
"the velocity dividend" that a government reaps from implementing a regime change that sustains a permanently lower inflation rate.
@@ -503,16 +487,15 @@ The following code does the calculations and plots outcomes.
Another lecture {doc}`monetarist theory of price levels with adaptive expectations <cagan_adaptive>` describes an "adaptive expectations" version of Cagan's model.
685
672
686
673
The dynamics become more complicated and so does the algebra.
687
674
688
-
Nowadays, the "rational expectations" version of the model is more popular among central bankers and economists advising them.
675
+
Nowadays, the "rational expectations" version of the model is more popular among central bankers and economists advising them.
0 commit comments