You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
This updates lecture money_inflation.md according to #437. In particular, it involves,
## Code
- Remove the grid in the plot
- Use `solve` to calculate the inverse
## Content
- Change bold non-definition words to italics
- $m_{t+1}^d/p_t =\gamma_1 - \gamma_2 \frac{p_{t+1}}{p_t}, \quad t \geq 0$ -> $\frac{m_{t+1}^d}{p_t} =\gamma_1 - \gamma_2 \frac{p_{t+1}}{p_t}, \quad t \geq 0$ where $\gamma_1$ and $\gamma_2$ are positive parameters.
- Remove the repetition of definition of $b_t$ and $R_{t-1}$
- Remove the $()$ in 26.6
- Check capitalization for titles
- gross rates of return on currency -> gross rates of return on currency and real balance
- $\bar R < 1$ -> $\bar R \le 1$
- $\bar R \in [\frac{\gamma2}{\gamma1}, 1]
\equiv [\underline R, \overline R]$ -> $\bar R \in [\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, 1] \equiv [\underline R, \overline R]$
- $R_t \in \bar R = [\underline R, \overline R], \quad t \geq 0$ -> $R_t \in [\underline R, \overline R], \quad t \geq 0$
- two values of $R$ -> Two steady-state values of $R$
- $R_l$ ->$R_\ell$
- An equilibrium sequences are not unique -> equilibrium sequences are not unique
- Remove the repetitive
```
$$\begin{aligned}
b_t & = b_{t-1} R_{t-1} + g \cr
R_t^{-1} & = \frac{\gamma_1}{\gamma_2} - \gamma_2^{-1} b_t
\end{aligned}$$
```
- "code plot outcomes" -> "code plot to outcomes"
- Set $ \Lambda= \begin{bmatrix} {R_l}^{-1} & 0 \cr
0 & {R_u}^{-1} \end{bmatrix}$
- $Q y_0 = y^*_0 = \begin{bmatrix} y^*_{1,0} \cr 0 \end{bmatrix}$ -> $Q^{-1} y_0 = y^*_0 = \begin{bmatrix} y^*_{1,0} \cr 0 \end{bmatrix}$.
Copy file name to clipboardExpand all lines: lectures/money_inflation.md
+47-59Lines changed: 47 additions & 59 deletions
Original file line number
Diff line number
Diff line change
@@ -33,7 +33,7 @@ The law of motion for the supply of money assumes that the government prints mon
33
33
Our model equates the demand for money to the supply at each time $t \geq 0$.
34
34
35
35
Equality between those demands and supply gives in a **dynamic** model in which money supply
36
-
and price level **sequences** are simultaneously determined by a set of simultaneous linear equations.
36
+
and price level *sequences* are simultaneously determined by a set of simultaneous linear equations.
37
37
38
38
These equations take the form of what are often called vector linear **difference equations**.
39
39
@@ -47,7 +47,7 @@ In this lecture we will encounter these concepts from macroeconomics:
47
47
* an **inflation tax** that a government gathers by printing paper or electronic money
48
48
* a dynamic **Laffer curve** in the inflation tax rate that has two stationary equilibria
49
49
* perverse dynamics under rational expectations in which the system converges to the higher stationary inflation tax rate
50
-
* a peculiar comparative stationary-state outcome connected with that stationary inflation rate: it asserts that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources by printing money.
50
+
* a peculiar comparative stationary-state outcome connected with that stationary inflation rate: it asserts that inflation can be *reduced* by running *higher* government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources by printing money.
51
51
52
52
The same qualitive outcomes prevail in this lecture {doc}`money_inflation_nonlinear` that studies a nonlinear version of the model in this lecture.
53
53
@@ -56,8 +56,8 @@ These outcomes set the stage for the analysis to be presented in this lecture {
56
56
That lecture will show that
57
57
58
58
* replacing rational expectations with adaptive expectations leaves the two stationary inflation rates unchanged, but that $\ldots$
59
-
* it reverse the pervese dynamics by making the **lower** stationary inflation rate the one to which the system typically converges
60
-
* a more plausible comparative dynamic outcome emerges in which now inflation can be **reduced** by running **lower** government deficits
59
+
* it reverse the pervese dynamics by making the *lower* stationary inflation rate the one to which the system typically converges
60
+
* a more plausible comparative dynamic outcome emerges in which now inflation can be *reduced* by running *lower* government deficits
61
61
62
62
This outcome will be used to justify a selection of a stationary inflation rate that underlies the analysis of unpleasant monetarist arithmetic to be studies in this lecture {doc}`unpleasant`.
63
63
@@ -68,9 +68,9 @@ We'll use theses tools from linear algebra:
68
68
* eigenvalues and eigenvectors of a matrix
69
69
70
70
71
-
## Demand for and Supply of Money
71
+
## Demand for and supply of money
72
72
73
-
We say demand**s** and suppl**ies** (plurals) because there is one of each for each $t \geq 0$.
73
+
We say demand*s* and suppl*ies* (plurals) because there is one of each for each $t \geq 0$.
74
74
75
75
Let
76
76
@@ -82,7 +82,7 @@ Let
82
82
* $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t}$ is real balances at the end of time $t$
83
83
* $R_t = \frac{p_t}{p_{t+1}} $ be the gross rate of return on currency held from time $t$ to time $t+1$
84
84
85
-
It is often helpful to state units in which quantities are measured:
85
+
It is often helpful to state units in which quantities are measured:
86
86
87
87
* $m_t$ and $m_t^d$ are measured in dollars
88
88
* $g$ is measured in time $t$ goods
@@ -96,8 +96,9 @@ Our job now is to specify demand and supply functions for money.
96
96
We assume that the demand for currency satisfies the Cagan-like demand function
97
97
98
98
$$
99
-
m_{t+1}^d/p_t=\gamma_1 - \gamma_2 \frac{p_{t+1}}{p_t}, \quad t \geq 0
99
+
\frac{m_{t+1}^d}{p_t}=\gamma_1 - \gamma_2 \frac{p_{t+1}}{p_t}, \quad t \geq 0
100
100
$$ (eq:demandmoney)
101
+
where $\gamma_1, \gamma_2$ are positive parameters.
101
102
102
103
Now we turn to the supply of money.
103
104
@@ -125,7 +126,7 @@ The demand for money at any time $t$ depends on the price level at time $t$ and
125
126
126
127
The supply of money at time $t+1$ depends on the money supply at time $t$ and the price level at time $t$.
127
128
128
-
So the infinite sequence of equations {eq}`eq:syeqdemand` for $ t \geq 0$ imply that the **sequences** $\{p_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ and $\{m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ are tied together and ultimately simulataneously determined.
129
+
So the infinite sequence of equations {eq}`eq:syeqdemand` for $ t \geq 0$ imply that the *sequences* $\{p_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ and $\{m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ are tied together and ultimately simulataneously determined.
129
130
130
131
131
132
## Equilibrium price and money supply sequences
@@ -144,11 +145,6 @@ $$
144
145
b_t - b_{t-1} R_{t-1} = g
145
146
$$ (eq:bmotion)
146
147
147
-
where
148
-
149
-
* $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t}$ is real balances at the end of period $t$
150
-
* $R_{t-1} = \frac{p_{t-1}}{p_t}$ is the gross rate of return on real balances held from $t-1$ to $t$
151
-
152
148
The demand for real balances is
153
149
154
150
$$
@@ -178,11 +174,11 @@ In a steady state equilibrium, a subset of key variables remain constant or **i
178
174
179
175
Finding such state variables is something of an art.
180
176
181
-
In many models, a good source of candidates for such invariant variables is a set of **ratios**.
177
+
In many models, a good source of candidates for such invariant variables is a set of *ratios*.
182
178
183
179
This is true in the present model.
184
180
185
-
### Steady States
181
+
### Steady states
186
182
187
183
In a **steady state** equilibrium of the model we are studying,
188
184
@@ -195,9 +191,9 @@ $$
195
191
196
192
for $t \geq 0$.
197
193
198
-
Notice that both $R_t = \frac{p_t}{p_{t+1}}$ and $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t} $ are **ratios**.
194
+
Notice that both $R_t = \frac{p_t}{p_{t+1}}$ and $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t} $ are *ratios*.
199
195
200
-
To compute a steady state, we seek gross rates of return on currency $\bar R, \bar b$ that satisfy steady-state versions of both the government budget constraint and the demand function for real balances:
196
+
To compute a steady state, we seek gross rates of return on currency and real balances $\bar R, \bar b$ that satisfy steady-state versions of both the government budget constraint and the demand function for real balances:
201
197
202
198
$$
203
199
\begin{aligned}
@@ -213,7 +209,7 @@ $$
213
209
$$ (eq:seignsteady)
214
210
215
211
216
-
The left side is the steady-state amount of **seigniorage** or government revenues that the government gathers by paying a gross rate of return $\bar R < 1$ on currency.
212
+
The left side is the steady-state amount of **seigniorage** or government revenues that the government gathers by paying a gross rate of return $\bar R \le 1$ on currency.
Now let's compute the maximum steady state amount of seigniorage that could be gathered by printing money and the state state rate of return on money that attains it.
358
353
359
-
## Two Computation Strategies
354
+
## Two computation strategies
360
355
361
356
We now proceed to compute equilibria, not necessarily steady states.
**Remark 1:** method 1 uses an indirect approach to computing an equilibrium by first computing an equilibrium $\{R_t, b_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ sequence and then using it to back out an equilibrium $\{p_t, m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ sequence.
394
389
395
390
396
-
**Remark 2:** notice that method 1 starts by picking an **initial condition** $R_0$ from a set $[\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, R_u]$. An equilibrium $\{p_t, m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ sequences are not unique. There is actually a continuum of equilibria indexed by a choice of $R_0$ from the set $[\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, R_u]$.
391
+
**Remark 2:** notice that method 1 starts by picking an **initial condition** $R_0$ from a set $[\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, R_u]$. Equilibrium $\{p_t, m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty$ sequences are not unique. There is actually a continuum of equilibria indexed by a choice of $R_0$ from the set $[\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, R_u]$.
397
392
398
393
**Remark 3:** associated with each selection of $R_0$ there is a unique $p_0$ described by
399
394
equation {eq}`eq:p0fromR0`.
@@ -425,37 +420,30 @@ It is natural to take the initial stock of money $m_0 >0$ as an initial conditio
425
420
426
421
But what about $p_0$?
427
422
428
-
Isn't it something that we want to be **determined** by our model?
423
+
Isn't it something that we want to be *determined* by our model?
429
424
430
425
Yes, but sometimes we want too much, because there is actually a continuum of initial $p_0$ levels that are compatible with the existence of an equilibrium.
431
426
432
427
As we shall see soon, selecting an initial $p_0$ in method 2 is intimately tied to selecting an initial rate of return on currency $R_0$ in method 1.
433
428
434
-
## Computation Method 1
429
+
## Computation method 1
435
430
436
431
%We start from an arbitrary $R_0$ and $b_t = \frac{m_{t+1}}{p_t}$, we have
437
432
438
433
%$$
439
434
%b_0 = \gamma_1 - \gamma_0 R_0^{-1}
440
435
%$$
441
436
442
-
Remember that there exist two steady state equilibrium values $ R_l < R_u$ of the rate of return on currency $R_t$.
437
+
Remember that there exist two steady state equilibrium values $ R_\ell < R_u$ of the rate of return on currency $R_t$.
443
438
444
439
We proceed as follows.
445
440
446
441
Start at $t=0$
447
442
* select a $R_0 \in [\frac{\gamma_2}{\gamma_1}, R_u]$
Please notice that for $m_t$ and $p_t$, we have used log scales for the coordinate (i.e., vertical) axes.
943
931
944
932
Using log scales allows us to spot distinct constant limiting gross rates of growth ${R_u}^{-1}$ and
945
-
${R_l}^{-1}$ by eye.
933
+
${R_\ell}^{-1}$ by eye.
946
934
947
935
948
936
## Peculiar stationary outcomes
@@ -952,13 +940,13 @@ As promised at the start of this lecture, we have encountered these concepts fro
952
940
* an **inflation tax** that a government gathers by printing paper or electronic money
953
941
* a dynamic **Laffer curve** in the inflation tax rate that has two stationary equilibria
954
942
955
-
Staring at the paths of rates of return on the price level in figure {numref}`R0_path` and price levels in {numref}`p0_path` show indicate that almost all paths converge to the **higher** inflation tax rate displayed in the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`.
943
+
Staring at the paths of rates of return on the price level in figure {numref}`R0_path` and price levels in {numref}`p0_path` show indicate that almost all paths converge to the *higher* inflation tax rate displayed in the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`.
956
944
957
945
Thus, we have indeed discovered what we earlier called "perverse" dynamics under rational expectations in which the system converges to the higher of two possible stationary inflation tax rates.
958
946
959
947
Those dynamics are "perverse" not only in the sense that they imply that the monetary and fiscal authorities that have chosen to finance government expenditures eventually impose a higher inflation tax than required to finance government expenditures, but because of the following "counterintuitive" situation that we can deduce by staring at the stationary state Laffer curve displayed in figure {numref}`infl_tax`:
960
948
961
-
* the figure indicates that inflation can be **reduced** by running **higher** government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources through printing money.
949
+
* the figure indicates that inflation can be *reduced* by running *higher* government deficits, i.e., by raising more resources through printing money.
962
950
963
951
964
952
```{note}
@@ -976,7 +964,7 @@ Through application of our computational methods 1 and 2, we have learned that
976
964
* for computational method 1, $R_0$
977
965
* for computational method 2, $p_0$
978
966
979
-
To apply our model, we have somehow to **complete** it by **selecting** an equilibrium path from among the continuum of possible paths.
967
+
To apply our model, we have somehow to **complete** it by *selecting* an equilibrium path from among the continuum of possible paths.
0 commit comments